Surprisingly,
central banks only possess limited toolboxes. Ailing economies don't always
respond to same-old remedies, no matter how nuanced or tailored those remedies
are purported to be. However, the banks have recently embarked on a very
unusual route; a route which could lead to an almost deliberately stoked global
recession.
This unusual
pathway will likely compound any brewing recessionary pressures as, when (or
if) the spectre of an economic downturn becomes a reality. Banks are
openly fessing up about economic hardships that their policies are causing but
have fallen short of sticking their hands up and admitting that it's the least
well off who are most likely to experience the roughest trot. Naturally, a
prolonged inflationary cycle isn't great for most people, so central banks
portray themselves as being a proactive force honing an environment of economic
stability.
Tentative easing
I have
questioned, in a previous article here in The Portugal News, whether
rate-driven inflation reduction schemes generate noticeably different results
compared with what might happen without such intervention? Right now, inflation
appears to be showing some tentative signs of easing, albeit more gradually
than many had hoped for a year ago (before Putin's war in Ukraine).
The problem we
seem to have is that the current inflation story is, in itself, extraordinary.
Usually, inflation is seeded amidst the melee of an overheating economy which
compounds consumerism and leads to stress within supply chains. This scenario
inevitably leads to incremental price hikes which gradually push up inflation.
In such instances, tightening monetary policies has the desired effect of
calming things down in a relatively controlled and organic manner.
Credit crunch
This time,
however, things have been markedly different. Many of our current woes have
come about as a direct result of past central bank interventions, going back as
far as 2008 (in the wake of the so-called 'credit crunch'). Central banks
printed money like never before in an attempt to monetise economies. At the
same time, interest rates plummeted for a prolonged period and the world became
reliant on cheap money. This meant that base rates only had one direction to
go. Up! It was simply a case of when, not if, because the status quo was
clearly unsustainable.
Just when
there were tentative signs of a post 2008 economic recovery – Covid-19 visited
the world and yet more quantitative easing and emergency rate cuts were imposed
on already shaky economies. As lockdowns took hold, it brought the entire
global supply chain to a halt.
Once lockdowns
eased and economic activity began to recover, commodities as well as
manufactured goods became increasingly scarce at a time when economies were
awash with an abundance of QE cash. Eminent economists warned that inflation
was bound to make a return as an inevitable consequence of central bank
interventions coupled with the unintended consequences of Covid-19 lockdowns.
Inflationary signs soon became all too evident. For example, the price of new
cars rocketed because there had been a drastic shortage of microchips causing
dealership inventories to plummet. Even before the war in Ukraine, energy
prices soared along with post-Covid-19 demand.
These days
many Covid-19 bottlenecks have been addressed which has greatly increased new
car inventories and helped reduce prices. At time of writing, oil prices are
also in decline. The falling cost of renewables implies that the price of crude
oil is likely to fall even further in the long term.
Better insulation
The one major
takeaway we can gather from Putin's war in Ukraine is that individual territories
need to do as much as they can to better insulate themselves from volatile food
and fuel prices. Besides the environmental plusses this scenario might create,
such action clearly means that we'd all be far less vulnerable to the whims of
despots like Vladimir Putin who continue to use the fruits of their
breadbaskets and petrochemical industries to hold western economies to ransom.
Historical evidence demonstrates how oil-rich regimes have cynically contrived
to use hiked fossil fuel prices as a lever to influence the direction of
western elections. Of course, Putin isn't the only leader of an oil-rich
country to have used such tried and tested tactics.
The current
cost of living crisis has headlined nearly every recent news bulletin amidst
threats of numerous strikes. Add to this, the talk of impending winter power
outages and it suddenly begins to look frighteningly similar to a vintage
1970's "winter of discontent." When all is said and done, contentment
appears to be in very short supply right now, particularly in the UK with its
rapid-fire Prime Ministerial about-changes and its embarrassing back catalogue
of embittered political rancour.
But the continued
scope for hiking prices can only go so far before hitting the buffers. Most
economists will declare that the best cure for high prices is high prices.
There comes a point when the affordability factor ebbs away thus creating
demand destruction. However, as the global economy emerges from the depths of
pandemic downsides, prices should begin to moderate and inflation will calm by
default.
In recent
months wages have been rising faster than they did pre-pandemic. But this ought
to be a positive because low wages obviously compound inequality and exacerbate
ingrained social disquietude. However, there have been recent falls in workers’
salaries when inflation-adjusted take-home pay is calculated. This exaggerated
sense of inequality sparked off the current spate of industrial action.
Let's revisit
the central policy question. Will higher interest rates increase the supply of
microchips for the automotive industry or compel petrostates like Russia
to pump more oil? Somehow, I don't think so. Will interest rate hikes compel
food producers to lower the price of their produce, other than by defaultly
reducing global incomes so people might end up cutting their diets and perhaps
cause a glut? Hardly likely.
Who pays?
Studies have
in fact demonstrated that higher interest rates could make it more difficult
for companies to invest in a way that helps alleviate supply shortages. There
are many other ways that higher interest rates may exacerbate inflationary
pressures because banks are making money more expensive. Who will ultimately
pay? Yes, you've got it. We ALL will.
Quite frankly,
interest rate hikes alone are a very blunt instrument and have morphed to be
central banks' go-to quick-fix. But like all harsh medicine, it's only useful
when administered swiftly, before any maladies take hold and become too firmly
entrenched.
There's so
much that's out of sync these days. Even well-directed fiscal and monetary
policies face obstacles. Take high rents for example. The UK has seen
immigration numbers soar but it's happened at a time when there's a chronic
housing shortage. Such shortages have facilitated an environment of high rents
which will surely only be compounded by presenting landlords with higher
interest repayments.
After more
than ten years of unprecedented low-interest rates, normalisation was
eventually an inevitability. But raising interest rates beyond what's deemed
normal in order to swiftly calm inflation will not just mean pain right now
but, like all bad tasting medicine, could create some of those dreaded
unintended consequences at a time when we don't need any further economic
shocks.
Douglas Hughes is a UK-based writer producing general interest articles ranging from travel pieces to classic motoring.